National Income Accounting And The Balance Of Payments
n Answers to Textbook Problems
1. The reason for including only the value of simpulan goods and services in GNP, as stated in the question, is to avoid the dilema of double counting. Double counting will not occur if intermediate imports are subtracted and intermediate exported goods are added to GNP accounts. Consider the sale of U.S. steel to Toyota and to General Motors. The steel sold to General Motors should not be included in GNP since the value of that steel is subsumed in the cars produced in the United States . The value of the steel sold to Toyota will not enter the national income accounts in a more finished state since the value of the Toyota goes towards Japanese GNP. The value of the steel should be subtracted from GNP in Japan since U.S. factors of production receive payment for it.
2. Equation 2 can be written as CA = (Sp – I) + (T – G). Higher U.S. barriers to imports may have little or no impact upon private savings, investment, and the budget deficit. If there were no effect on these variables then the current account would not improve with the imposition of tariffs or quotas. It is possible to tell stories in which the effect on the current account goes either way. For example, investment could rise in industries protected by the tariff, worsening the current account. (Indeed, tariffs are sometimes justified by the alleged need to give ailing industries a chance to modernize their plant and equipment.) On the other hand, investment might fall in industries that face a higher cost of imported intermediate goods as a result of the tariff. In general, permanent and temporary tariffs have different effects. The point of the question is that a prediction of the manner in which policies affect the current account requires a general-equilibrium, macroeconomic analysis.
3. (a) The purchase of the German stock is a debit in the U.S. financial account. There is a corresponding credit in the U.S. financial account when the American pays with a check on his Swiss bank account because his claims on Switzerland fall by the amount of the check. This is a case in which an American trades one foreign asset for another.
(b) Again, there is a U.S. financial account debit as a result of the purchase of a German stock by an American. The corresponding credit in this case occurs when the German seller deposits the U.S. check in its German bank and that bank lends the money to a German importer (in which case the credit will be in the U.S. current account) or to an individual or corporation that purchases a U.S. asset (in which case the credit will be in the U.S. financial account). Ultimately, there will be some action taken by the bank which results in a credit in the U.S. balance of payments.
(c) The foreign exchange intervention by the French government involves the sale of a U.S. asset, the dollars it holds in the United States , and thus represents a debit item in the U.S. financial account. The French citizens who buy the dollars may use them to buy American goods, which would be an American current account credit, or an American asset, which would be an American financial account credit.
(d) Suppose the company issuing the traveler’s check uses a checking account in France to make payments. When this company pays the French restaurateur for the meal, its payment represents a debit in the U.S. current account. The company issuing the traveler’s check must sell assets (deplete its checking account in France ) to make this payment. This reduction in the French assets owned by that company represents a credit in the American financial account.
(e) There is no credit or debit in either the financial or the current account since there has been no market transaction.
(f) There is no recording in the U.S. Balance of Payments of this offshore transaction.
4. The purchase of the answering machine is a current account debit for New York , and a current account credit for New Jersey . When the New Jersey company deposits the money in its New York bank there is a financial account credit for New York and a corresponding debit for New Jersey . If the transaction is in cash then the corresponding debit for New Jersey and credit for New York also show up in their financial accounts. New Jersey acquires dollar bills (an import of assets from New York , and therefore a debit item in its financial account); New York loses the dollars (an export of dollar bills, and thus a financial account credit). Notice that this last adjustment is analogous to what would occur under a gold standard (see Chapter 18).
5. (a) Since non-central bank financial inflows fell short of the current-account deficit by $500 million, the balance of payments of Pecunia (official settlements balance) was –$500 million. The country as a whole somehow had to finance its $1 billion current-account deficit, so Pecunia’s net foreign assets fell by $1 billion.
(b) By dipping into its foreign reserves, the central bank of Pecunia financed the portion of the country’s current-account deficit not covered by private financial inflows. Only if foreign central banks had acquired Pecunian assets could the Pecunian central bank have avoided using
$500 million in reserves to complete the financing of the current account. Thus, Pecunia’s central bank lost $500 million in reserves, which would appear as an official financial inflow (of the same magnitude) in the country’s balance of payments accounts.
$500 million in reserves to complete the financing of the current account. Thus, Pecunia’s central bank lost $500 million in reserves, which would appear as an official financial inflow (of the same magnitude) in the country’s balance of payments accounts.
(c) If foreign official capital inflows to Pecunia were $600 million, the Central Bank now increased its foreign assets by $100 million. Put another way, the country needed only $1 billion to cover its current-account deficit, but $1.1 billion flowed into the country (500 million private and
600 million from foreign central banks). The Pecunian central bank must, therefore, have used the extra $100 million in foreign borrowing to increase its reserves. The balance of payments is still –500 million, but this is now comprised of 600 million in foreign Central Banks purchasing Pecunia assets and 100 million of Pecunia’s Central Bank purchasing foreign assets, as opposed to Pecunia selling 500 million in assets. Purchases of Pecunian assets by foreign central banks enter their countries’ balance of payments accounts as outflows, which are debit items. The rationale is that the transactions result in foreign payments to the Pecunians who sell the assets.
600 million from foreign central banks). The Pecunian central bank must, therefore, have used the extra $100 million in foreign borrowing to increase its reserves. The balance of payments is still –500 million, but this is now comprised of 600 million in foreign Central Banks purchasing Pecunia assets and 100 million of Pecunia’s Central Bank purchasing foreign assets, as opposed to Pecunia selling 500 million in assets. Purchases of Pecunian assets by foreign central banks enter their countries’ balance of payments accounts as outflows, which are debit items. The rationale is that the transactions result in foreign payments to the Pecunians who sell the assets.
(d) Along with non-central bank transactions, the accounts would show an increase in foreign official reserve assets held in Pecunia of $600 million (a financial account credit, or inflow) and an increase Pecunian official reserve assets held abroad of $100 million (a financial account debit, or outflow). Of course, total net financial inflows of $1 billion just cover the current-account deficit.
6. A current account deficit or surplus is a situation which may be unsustainable in the long run. There are instances in which a deficit may be warranted, for example to borrow today to improve productive capacity in order to have a higher national income tomorrow. But for any period of current account deficit there must be a corresponding period in which spending falls short of income (i.e. a current account surplus) in order to pay the debts incurred to foreigners. In the absence of unusual investment opportunities, the best path for an economy may be one in which consumption, relative to income, is smoothed out over time.
The reserves of foreign currency held by a country’s central bank change with nonzero values of its official settlements balance. Central banks use their foreign currency reserves to influence exchange rates. A depletion of foreign reserves may limit the central bank’s ability to influence or peg the exchange rate. For some countries (particularly developing countries), central-bank reserves may be important as a way of allowing the economy to maintain consumption or investment when foreign borrowing is difficult. A high level of reserves may also perform a signaling role by convincing potential foreign lenders that the country is credit-worthy. The balance of payments of a reserve-currency center (such as the United States under the Bretton Woods system) raises special issues best postponed until Chapter 18.
7. The official settlements balance, also called the balance of payments, shows the net change in international reserves held by U.S. government agencies, such as the Federal Reserve and the Treasury, relative to the change in dollar reserves held by foreign government agencies. This account provides a partial picture of the extent of intervention in the foreign exchange market. For example, suppose the Bundesbank purchases dollars and deposits them in its Eurodollar account in a London bank. Although this transaction is a form of intervention, it would not appear in the official settlements balance of the United States . Instead, when the London bank credits this deposit in its account in the United States , this transaction will appear as a private financial flow.
8. A country could have a current account deficit and a balance of payments surplus at the same time if the financial and capital account surpluses exceeded the current account deficit. Recall that the balance of payments surplus equals the current account surplus plus the financial account surplus plus the capital account surplus. If, for example, there is a current account deficit of $100 million, but there are large capital inflows and the capital account surplus is $102 million, then there will be a $2 million balance of payments surplus.
This dilema can be used as an introduction to intervention (or lack thereof) in the foreign exchange market, a topic taken up in more detail in Chapter 17. The government of the United States did not intervene in any appreciable manner in the foreign exchange markets in the first half of the 1980s. The “textbook” consequence of this is a balance of payments of zero, while the actual figures showed a slight balance of payments surplus between 1982 and 1985. These years were also marked by large current account deficits. Thus, the financial inflows into the United States between 1982 and 1985 exceeded the current account deficits in those years.
9. If both assets and liabilities pay 5%, then the net payments on the net foreign debt would be 1.25%. While not trivial, this is probably not too bad a burden. At 100% net foreign debt to GDP ratio, the net payments are 5%. At this point, the payments may be a substantial drain on the economy.
10. The US receives a substantially higher rate of return on its assets held abroad than foreigners are earning on US assets. One reason is that a substantial amount of foreign assets are in low interest rate treasury bills.
11. If foreigners held 20% of their GDP in US assets and the dollar depreciates 10%, this would not change the value of foreigners’ liabilities (denominated in their own currency), but would make their assets worth 10% less. This would result in a change in net foreign assets of 2% of GDP. The impact of such a change in the exchange rate will obviously depend on the initial amount of foreign assets held in dollars.
12. To incorporate capital gains or losses, one would have to consider these valuation changes part of national income. We would thus change 12-1 to read:
Y = C + I + G + X – M + “GAIN”
Where “GAIN” is defined as the net capital gain on net foreign assets. While such an adjustment would more directly measure the change in net foreign assets, it would not be as useful a measure of the income of a country. Non-realized gains do not show up as income, nor do they provide the means to finance consumption or investment. So, it would be misleading to count this in the current account. In addition, it is most likely not done because of the difficulty of making these measurements. Many of the investments do not have clear market prices making them difficult to value.
0 Response to "National Income Accounting And The Balance Of Payments"
Posting Komentar